The leader of the Opposition, Ranil
Wickremesinghe is proposing a much needed public discussion on
what should be the ‘podu yahapatha’ or the common good of
Sri Lanka. The proposals yet to be published in detail at the
time this article is written, in essence suggest, it is said,
that our common good should be based on democracy and the market
economy. ( Divaina, 21/01/2005)
The majoritarian, representative democracy with
all its inherent weaknesses, and made much weaker in the Sri
Lankan context, however, has come to stay in Sri Lanka.
Abolishing the executive Presidency which centralises draconian
powers in the hands of one individual who is not accountable to
the law of the country, and therefore weakens the strength of
our democracy, would be a definite move in the direction of
improving upon our democracy.
The market as a legitimate part of the economy
has also come to stay even though the manner in which the
dominance of it was forced upon us in the post-1977 period has
wreaked havoc on the Sri Lankan society, the unfolding of the
serious ramifications of which will take a long time to come, as
shown by one of its prime examples, the privatized public
transport, experienced by the ordinary folk who travel around by
bus. The real issue about the market is not whether it can be
considered a legitimate partner in the national economy, but
whether we want to accept the market as the guiding principle of
our collective life. If the results of the last general election
is any indication to go by, then the message from the large
majority of the Sri Lankan public seems to be a resounding NO!
However, even after the debacle at the last elections, in
proposing this, what Ranil Wickremesinghe is proposing to have,
in fact is a public debate on the neo-liberal economic policies
even though one may wonder whether it is already not too late to
have this debate now!
When we say that the Industrialised western
countries or countries such as Singapore have achieved high
levels of ‘development’ following the model of democracy and
market economy, what we express seems to be our fond hope that
Sri Lanka also can be ‘developed’ following the same model,
rather than being realistic on how different countries achieve
‘development’ each in its own unique way, subject to specific
historical conditions and cultural factors. It is also outside
the consideration whether we in Sri Lanka would necessarily want
to follow such a model of development even if we could succeed
in such an attempt. Our penchant for Singapore as the model of
development may be due to our desire to find an easy solution to
the messy situation of being citizens of a country full of
internal strife in all areas of collective life that do not seem
to be resolvable ever. It is no wonder that in a context where
there is so much of conflict, instability and social unrest,
many of us would dream of doing a Lee Kwan-Yew in Sri Lanka as
if human world can be put in order by the sleight of hand of a
clever magician. We need to remind ourselves that even Singapore
itself could produce only one Lee Kwan Yew in its life time. But
more importantly, even if one of us is clever enough to become a
Lee Kwan Yew as if by a secret magical act, the possibility is
that being the political beings that they are, Sri Lankans would
not tolerate a Lee Kwan Yew in their midst.
While the Fukuyama doctrine of End of History
which can be taken to mean that the unfolding of history in the
world culminates in the entire world embracing neo-liberal
economic policies which give dominance to the free reign of
market forces, may seem to sound generally valid in the
aftermath of the collapse of the state-centred economies of the
socialist bloc countries, one cannot necessarily conclude from
the latter event that politics has come to an end, or for that
matter should come to an end, even in a world dominated by
liberalism. The dominance of liberalism itself is the reason to
revive our sense of politics, to preserve and advance the
political gains won by the public in such a world, as otherwise
unhindered liberalism tend to be heading in a direction which
generates forces of self-destruction within its own territory.
This is in addition to the resentment generated from without
liberalism against it due to the action of its overzealous
advocates to export liberal democracy by force to the
territories of the ‘non-believers.’
The State or the Market? Both!
The other side of neoliberal myth that insists
markets can solve every problem is the belief that the
government can do little other than making the life of people
difficult. Neo-liberalism turns the idea of collective good into
an issue between the free market economy and the government. To
pose the question in terms of whether to choose between the
private capitalist sector and the government which is the
political instrument of the collective life is to raise a
red-herring.
On the other hand, the state centred economy is
not the only option to market-centred economy. In industrialised
countries in the West, one finds the state playing a
considerable, if not a major role, in maintaining the important
sectors of public transport, health care, education, child care,
taking care of the elderly and welfare assistance in varying
degrees. Quite a few of these countries have a strong welfare
system which is jealously guarded against the intrusions of
immigrants from the poor countries.
Nevertheless, we must commend Ranil
Wickremesinghe for being courageous to stand by his convictions
and willing to raise his vision of the common good for public
debate thus throwing the gauntlet at other political parties and
leaders who will be forced to articulate their visions for the
common good of Sri Lanka.
Hence, if the public rises to the occasion
taking the cue from Ranil Wickremesinghe and challenge all
political parties to clearly articulate their visions for the
common good of the country for public scrutiny, this may very
will be the opportunity Sri Lanka has been waiting for its
national re-awakening!
In my view, it is a sensible idea to agree that
the priority given to the market mechanism in certain areas is a
necessary component of the national economy as we have already
come to realise and accept now in practice, instead of going
back to a fully state regulated economy, the latter being a move
which no one with a sense of practical reality would want to
suggest. However, what aspects of the economy, to which extent,
under what conditions should be subjected to the dictates of the
market, is a matter to be collectively decided on the merit of
each case, and therefore should not be a forgone conclusion that
accepts the virtue of the market forces as a panacea for all
ills in society. We know from our general experience that
allowing capitalism unhindered free play in the market place,
whether it is in production, trade or consumption has the
general tendency of bringing into the open the rapacious
character of individual human beings at the expense of public
interest.
By now, with the benefit of hindsight we should
be able to realise that the decision to privatize the public
transport subjecting it to the dictates of market forces was the
wrong decision. That it continues in its present form is only a
testimony to the priority given by our politicians and
bureaucrats to their ideologies and therefore the desire to
place the perceived benefits of the private bus operation to the
economy above the welfare of the ordinary public.
The helpless public who has no effective say in
determining how collective affairs are run, daily suffer in the
hands of private bus operators whose inhumanity towards fellow
public is guided solely by the profit motive. These private
operators of public transport have become a powerful political
force unto themselves and probably a vote bank. The public, I am
sure would be vigilantly watching the political alliances of
these bus operators when it comes to their decision to whom to
vote for in the elections. Anyone who takes the trouble to find
out about the public transport in industrialised countries in
the West will realise that in many cities in those countries
public transport is not run on the basis of profit but as a
public service, in most part funded by the city,
provincial/state and national/federal governments. It is so
because the public in those countries demand that the
governments treat their citizens with common decency and
consider that their labour force should have access to
comfortable and convenient transport as they make a valuable
contribution to the economy. Both the private sector in those
countries and their governments are sophisticated enough to know
that the productivity of labour increases under healthy working
conditions of which transport to and from work is an essential
part.
In fact, how we answer the question what sectors
of our public services should be privatized in what manner, is
not a secondary issue but one that is integral to, and hence one
that itself would reflect, our understanding of our common good.
In this sense any discussion of our common good need to go
beyond simply stating that it should be based on democracy and
market economy, but examine for which understanding of the
common good we want to have democracy and market economy as its
basis. I want to suggest that in determining what is our common
good, the crucial issue is whether our understanding of our good
life is one that gives priority to the individual good or the
collective good. This we will examine in the next part of this
article.
The writer could be contacted at: <citizen.ordinary@gmail.com>
(For some of the ideas in this article, the
writer is indebted to Benjamin R. Barber’s book Strong
Democracy, University of California Press ) .